Of
Course the Rich Are Getting Richer (Part 1)
Often there is one pay system for executives, the
intent of which
is to pay them as much as possible. There are other pay
systems
for managers and core workers. The intent of these
is to keep
labor costs as low as possible. . . . It is this
class distinction that
results in the incongruence of massive layoffs and
record
profits and executive bonuses all in the same year.
—Peter Block,
Stewardship
Though capitalists are also
consumers, a distinct class difference divides the two groups. That distinction
is revealed in the quotation from Peter Block above. A good definition of what
it means to be a capitalist is simply that a capitalist is paid as much as
possible. Why? Because capitalists control capital, and it is capital that
produces income. These people pay themselves as much as possible so that they
can accumulate more capital—not to spend on consumer items, but primarily to
reinvest in productive capacity, so that they can become even more wealthy and
control an even larger piece of the productive pie.
Noncapitalists, by contrast, do
not control capital, even when they invest their modest savings in stocks or
bonds. Noncapitalists, because they do not control capital, are paid as little
as possible (so that the capitalists can minimize costs and maximize profits).
What they take home in wages is called disposable income. Why? Because
they are supposed to dispose of it through consuming the products they produce.
They are not supposed to become more wealthy. As Galbraith points out, their
role in the economy is to consume.
The end result of this class
division is an ever-widening monetary gap between the capitalists and the
consumers. This is not a political phenomenon, nor is it the result of an
uncompetitive or misfiring economy. It is simply the logical consequence of the
capitalist system. Quite frequently I read articles in the newspaper expressing
dismay over the fact that the rich are still getting richer and the poor
relatively poorer. The articles always cite the most recent statistics, and the
writers are invariably aghast over this continuing trend.
This is an irrational reaction,
however, for capitalism is designed at its most fundamental levels to create
increasing inequality. Somewhere, I suppose, many of us got the idea that
capitalism and equality are compatible. Our reasoning must go something like
this: since egalitarianism is part of the American Dream, then American
capitalism should produce greater equality. This reasoning may be comfortable,
but it is also defective. Which mechanism in the capitalist machine, I would
ask, is supposed to equalize wealth? There is none.
Capitalism is genetically
predisposed to shift relative wealth from the poor to the rich, or, if you
prefer, from the unpropertied to the propertied. It’s simply the nature of the
beast. We can’t expect it to act other than it is designed to act. Let’s look
at this idea more closely.
The
“Leak-Through” Theory
I don’t pretend to know who first
came up with the notorious “trickle-down” theory. The term itself can be traced
to about 1954, although the concept is at least old enough that William
Jennings Bryan railed against it a century ago. Said the Great Commoner: “There
are those who believe that if you will legislate to make the well-to-do
prosperous, their prosperity will leak through on those below.”1 Bryan’s
“leak-through” theory is basically the same as today’s trickle-down theory,
which suggests that financial benefits given to the rich will filter on down to
lower economic levels. This may be true, but there is nothing in the
trickle-down theory to suggest that the lower levels of society will actually
increase their relative wealth, and it is relative wealth that we’re
talking about here.
When capitalism creates new
wealth, greater economic equality can result only if the capitalist class
passes on more wealth per capita than it retains. When has this ever
happened? Even the most rabid, bleeding-heart, Robin Hood liberal would never
dream of taking so much from the rich that the poor actually gain more wealth per
capita than their elite counterparts.
If the poorest 20 percent of
Americans get a trickle (or leak) of wealth, we can be sure that the rich are
receiving a flood. We’ve been told that a rising tide lifts all boats, but
today’s society can become more equal only if the rubber rafts and dinghies
rise faster than the yachts and cruise ships. Unfortunately, though, the old
“rising tide” maxim doesn’t hold water— because some of our individual boats
don’t either. The system has punched holes in our hulls, and no matter how high
the tide, we’re still going to sink.
There was a time when the poorest
levels of society were indeed receiving that infamous trickle of real wealth.
They may have been falling further behind the rich, but in real terms they were
able to improve their living standard. In recent years, however, both the poor
and those in the middle have not only fallen further behind the rich, they have
actually moved backwards in terms of real wealth. According to Robert Reich,
between 1977 and 1989 “the average after-tax incomes of American families in
the bottom fifth of the income ladder fell some 9 percent, the next fifth grew
6.5 percent poorer, and the middle fifth about 4.5 percent poorer. Only the top
fifth was spared. In fact, the higher reaches of the top fifth were not only
spared, their incomes soared. The incomes of those in the top 1 percent
actually doubled.”2
Reich attributes this growing
gap, particularly the downward movement of the lower and middle levels, to the
loss of manufacturing jobs. Between 1989 and November 1992, he says, 1.3
million manufacturing jobs were lost in the United States. Most of these
workers were forced into service jobs that paid only one-half to two-thirds of
typical manufacturing wages.
This is trickle-down economics of
the 1990s. Economic gains are defying gravity and trickling up. The lower
levels are losing ground, not just in a relative sense, but in a very real
sense.
Three
Types of Workers
The loss in manufacturing jobs is
the direct result of new technology that displaces labor and cheap foreign
competition that persuades executives to move manufacturing facilities abroad.
The rise of the global economy has created, among other effects, a sharp
division between various types of labor.
In his book The Work of
Nations, Reich identifies three separate categories of American workers
that are emerging with the global economy: routine producers, in-person
servers, and symbolic analysts. “No longer are Americans rising or
falling together, as if in one large national boat. We are, increasingly, in
different, smaller boats.”3 Of the three types of boats listed
above, only the third is rising with the economic tide. Let’s look briefly at
these three groups and how they are faring.
Routine producers are those who perform repetitive
tasks in the production of goods. This group includes not only blue-collar
manufacturing workers, but also employees involved in white-collar or high-tech
work. Data processors and programmers who devise routine coding for computer
software come to mind. In-person servers may also perform routine work,
but their services must be provided person-to-person. Retail sales workers,
waiters and waitresses, custodians, cashiers, house cleaners, hospital
attendants, taxi drivers, secretaries, auto mechanics, flight attendants, and
security guards are typical of this category. Symbolic analysts, by
contrast, engage in problem-identifying, problem-solving, decision-making, or
strategy-brokering activities. These workers may be researchers, scientists,
designers, engineers, public relations specialists, investment bankers,
lawyers, consultants, systems analysts, advertising executives, film editors,
art directors, architects, musicians, publishers, television producers,
university professors, or seminar presenters, to list just a few.
As discussed in the previous
chapter, routine production jobs are being lost continually to both foreign
competition and technological advances. The thirty-five hours it took auto
workers to assemble a car in 1977, for instance, has now been reduced to eight.
Nippon Steel and Inland Steel built a cold-rolling mill near Gary, Indiana, in
the late 1980s that cut the time to produce a coil of steel from twelve days to
about one hour.4 The masses of workers displaced by technology and
those entering the job market who are not qualified for symbolic-analytical
work must increasingly compete for low-paying in-person service jobs. There are
plenty of these, but intense competition keeps wages low.
The only jobs that show great
promise for the future involve data analysis and the manipulation of symbols.
Great demand exists in the global economy for scientific researchers,
management consultants, advertisers, architects, property developers, public
relations experts, civil engineers, political consultants, and even movie stars
and other entertainers. “Among the wealthiest symbolic analysts,” says Reich,
“are Steven Spielberg, Bill Cosby, Charles Schulz, Eddie Murphy, Sylvester
Stallone, Madonna, and other star directors and performers. . . . [And] behind
each of these familiar faces is a collection of American problem-solvers,
-identifiers, and brokers who train, coach, advise, promote, amplify, direct,
groom, represent, and otherwise add value to their talents.”5 These
symbolic-analysts may be employees, but their expertise is in such high demand
that they enjoy an independence and exert a level of control over their careers
and incomes undreamed of by either in-person servers or routine production
workers.
Perhaps the most important factor
influencing the workforce equation, however, is that there is not unlimited
demand for symbolic-analysts. One hundred percent of the employable population
cannot find work in these jobs. Only a minority can fit into this one rising
boat. The rest of us must compete for jobs in either a dwindling manufacturing
sector or an immense, low-paying service sector. The result is an increasingly
unequal society, one that can sustain neither economic nor social health. This
whole unfolding scenario leads us inevitably to a particularly uncomfortable
question: Is it perhaps time to rethink our centuries-old assumptions about
the division of labor and come to terms with what those assumptions have done
to our society?
Equality
The underlying issue here is
equality, which is a concept that in both theory and practice seems to give
nearly everyone dyspepsia. If we weren’t concerned about equality, we wouldn’t
even have an American Dream or social ideals, and we wouldn’t be troubled by
the increasing gap between rich and poor. We wouldn’t even bother trying to
justify the natural effects of capitalism. But we are concerned about
equality. It’s an integral part of the American psyche and the American Dream.
According to Webster’s, the American Dream is a “social ideal that stresses
egalitarianism and especially material prosperity.” If the two halves of this
definition seem incompatible, well, they are—given our current economic
assumptions. In our capitalist system, overall material prosperity comes only
at the expense of equality. Can the two ideas be reconciled? We certainly must
hope so, for equality is not merely an American ideal and a morally appealing
principle; some approximation of it is also necessary for long-term economic
health.
Thomas Jefferson declared in the
Declaration of Independence that “all men are created equal,” thus planting the
idea, as Frost put it, “where it will trouble us a thousand years.”6
Frost was right. Because Jefferson didn’t bother to explain exactly what he
meant by “equal,” we have been arguing about it already for more than two
hundred years.
For instance, do we mean equality
of opportunity or equality of outcome? It’s hard to guarantee equality of
outcome without removing people’s freedom entirely, for individuals possess
varying levels of intelligence, talent, and motivation. Equality of opportunity
is probably nearer the mark, but how do we guarantee everyone an equal
opportunity? This is actually the central question of this book, and I shall
attempt to answer it more fully in a later chapter, but for now let me merely
suggest that neither the liberals nor the conservatives offer a viable
solution.
It is also difficult to entirely
separate these two types of equality. When we talk about equality of
opportunity, we can’t just sweep equality of outcome under the rug, because it
is impossible to offer equal opportunity without requiring to some degree an
equality of outcome. As the natural mechanism of unbridled capitalism creates a
two-tiered society of haves and have-nots, the opportunities of some expand,
while the opportunities of the rest diminish. This creates a vicious circle.
Diminished opportunities translate directly into diminished outcomes, and
diminished outcomes, in turn, further curtail opportunities. We must,
therefore, address the complex problem of equal outcomes—not by redistributing
wealth, but by ensuring that opportunity is never hoarded by some and withheld
from others.
___________________
1.
George F. Will, “Kerry Exemplifies Double Dilemma of Democrats in 1996,” Deseret
News, December 4, 1994, sec. V, 6.
2. Robert B. Reich, “High-Wage Jobs Needed to Heal
Sick Economy,” Deseret News, November 5–6, 1992, sec. A, 15, reprinted
from New Perspectives Quarterly.
3. Robert B. Reich, The Work of Nations: Preparing
Ourselves for 21st-Century Capitalism (New York: Knopf, 1991), 171.
4.
Reich, Work of Nations, 214.
5.
Reich, Work of Nations, 220–21.
6.
Robert Frost, “The Black Cottage,” in The Poetry of Robert Frost, ed. E. C. Lathem (New York:
Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 1969), 57.