John Hobson, a frail little Englishman with a speech
impediment and a penchant for economic heresy, argued more than a century ago
that in order to grow, indeed, in order to survive, capitalism had to become
imperialistic. Without exporting both production capacity and products abroad,
capitalism would eventually suffocate itself. At the time, no one really took
him seriously, except the Marxists, who twisted his ideas into a strange
confirmation of their own misconceptions. But Hobson’s reasoning was both
fascinating and deceptively simple: growth, the very engine that drives
capitalism, also creates the conditions in which a nation can never consume
everything it produces.1
The poor, Hobson argued—and today we would add the middle
class—don’t have the means to buy their fair share of the nation’s production,
and the rich have too much money to consume a proportionate piece of the
productive pie. Someone with a $10 million income can’t (or won’t see any reason
to) buy two hundred times more consumer goods than a person with a $50,000
income. In fact, the wealthy in every society are mindful of what they don’t spend, for if they spend all they
have, they are no longer wealthy. Wealthy people, rather than spend most of
their income, invest a good portion of it, directly or indirectly, in new
productive capacity, which, Hobson insisted, merely compounds the problem. If
society is already having difficulty consuming all it produces, then this
perpetual increase in productive capacity will flood an already saturated
market.
In order to grow, Hobson concluded, capitalist economies
not only have to invest their capital abroad, they also have to sell their
increased production abroad. They have to export more than they import. From
one nation’s perspective, this provides a temporary respite, but in the long
run it ruins a world economy, as more and more nations need an outlet for their
excesses.
Hobson’s ideas, though largely forgotten, are nonetheless
significant, especially when seen in light of today’s global economy. For many
years after World War II, America was able to export more than it imported. But
now the tables are turned. For decades now, America has run up huge trade
deficits. In other words, we have somehow found a way to consume not only
everything we produce, but billions of dollars of goods imported from other
countries. How have we managed this?
It is simple, really. We have found a way around Hobson’s
insistence that capitalist societies cannot consume all they produce without
becoming imperialistic: debt. We are buying on credit. The problem with this
solution is obvious: eventually, as the world economy reaches the point America
reached a few decades ago and all nations sink deeper into debt, the global
economy will bankrupt itself. Because of the principle of compound interest, debt
has a tendency to grow exponentially and, in normal times, to outpace economic
growth. At present, interest rates are abnormally low, so we are experiencing a
brief reprieve, but, as they say, time will tell.
The root of Hobson’s dilemma, though, is the unequal
distribution of wealth. If the lower and middle classes had more disposable
income with which to purchase consumer goods, and if the wealthy had less
excess money to invest in unneeded production, would the system avoid its
inevitable demise? This is a good question, which lies beyond the scope of this
series of posts. For now, we need to address the question of profit.
The Profit Problem
John Hobson’s intriguing observations hint at the
underlying question introduced in the previous post: What makes the capitalist economy grow? The answer is simple:
profit. But where does profit come from? Profit in a single business is, of
course, the difference between revenues and expenses. It comes simply as
businesses charge more for their products than the sum of their expenses. But
the aggregate of all businesses should not be able to experience a profit
because all revenues and expenses should cancel each other out. This is the
problem that perplexed worldly philosophers for centuries. Curiously, only
three reasonable answers were ever put forward: one by Karl Marx, another by
Joseph Schumpeter, and a third by Thorstein Veblen. Even the venerable Adam
Smith wavered on this question between two possible answers.
For a detailed explanation of the three theories, I
recommend Robert Heilbroner’s classic The
Worldly Philosophers, but for our purposes here, let me try to fit these
three explanations into a very small nutshell. Marx concluded, as did others,
that profit doesn’t occur naturally in the capitalist system. Market forces
drive profit from the system whenever it rears its head, so Marx theorized that
the only way capitalists can extract a profit from their operations is to steal
it from the laborers by paying them less than their actual value. This theory
has some merit but also some obvious limitations, since it doesn’t address the
reality Hobson identified or answer the question posed by Hannah Bell (see last
week’s post).
To Schumpeter, profit was not stolen into existence;
rather, it came honestly from innovation. He described production and
consumption as a circular flow that follows a regular and predictable course:
people trading money and products with one another. Profits magically appear
whenever innovation disrupts the circular flow. Those who create the innovation
can charge a higher price or reduce their production costs and thus extract a
profit—until their competitors match the innovation and restore equilibrium.
Schumpeter’s theory offers a partial explanation, but it still does not answer
Hannah Bell’s question. Innovators may be able to charge more for their
products temporarily, but their revenues must still come from somewhere, and
that “somewhere” is, directly or indirectly, someone else’s expense, so
revenues and expenses still theoretically cancel each other out.
Veblen came at the profit problem from a different angle.
He saw “the economic process itself as being basically mechanical in character.
Economic meant production, and production meant the machinelike meshing of
society as it turned out goods. Such a social machine would need tenders, of
course—technicians and engineers to make whatever adjustments were necessary to
ensure the most efficient cooperation of the parts.”2
But where, asked Veblen, does the businessman fit in? The
businessman, he concluded, was basically a saboteur of the system who extracted
profit by disrupting its smooth, mechanical operation. The system saw no other
end except making goods. But the businessman was interested only in making
money. The problem with the economic machine, however, is that if it worked
efficiently, there would be no room for a man who only wanted to make a profit,
because profit would be squeezed out of the regular flow of production and
consumption. “So the businessman achieved his end not by working within the
system, but by conspiring against it. His real purpose was not to help make
goods, but to cause breakdowns in the regular flow of output so that values
would fluctuate and he could capitalize on the confusion to reap a profit.”3
And how did the businessman cause these breakdowns in the
production machinery? By creating the never-never-land of corporate finance.
Corporate capitalism isn’t just about producing motorcycles and mushrooms and
microchips. “On top of the machinelike dependability of the actual production
apparatus,” writes Heilbroner, explaining Veblen’s theory, “the businessman built
a superstructure of credit, loans, and make-believe capitalizations. Below,
society turned over in its mechanical routine; above, the structure of finance
swayed and shifted. And as the financial counterpart to the real world
teetered, opportunities for profit constantly appeared, disappeared, and
reappeared.”4
The Disconnected Financial System
All three of the theories about where profit comes from
in the capitalist system—the theories of Marx, Schumpeter, and Veblen—have
their merits, but they also have significant flaws. Indeed, none of these
theories actually explains how the capitalist economy expands and produces
profit. Veblen’s version, for instance, doesn’t really explain how ordinary
businesses that aren’t involved in financial manipulations can turn a profit,
but it certainly addresses what has been happening recently in the global
economy at large. As Wall Street has concocted a variety of “make-believe
capitalizations,” the financial sector has found ways to extract obscene
amounts of “profit” from the economy. In 2007, for instance, just before the
big financial meltdown, the top fifty private investment fund managers received
an average of $588 million each in annual compensation. The top five received
more than $1.5 billion each.5 And this is just the tip of the
iceberg. These firms were extracting phantom profits and paying out salaries
and bonuses in unheard-of quantities. Of course, when this house of cards
collapsed, it became obvious that these profits and outlandish compensation
packages were simply the effect of leveraging assets to the moon and back
through speculative financial instruments called derivatives. And since so much
money had been paid out in salaries and bonuses, there was not nearly enough
left in reserve to cover the losses, which compelled government to step in with
enormous bailouts to keep the entire economy from falling apart. Of course, the
recent Republican claims that we shouldn’t have bailed out Wall Street are
simply the blather of politicians who have no concept of what would have
happened if we hadn’t.
The idea of the bailouts was to clear out toxic debt and
get credit flowing again so that the economy could return to its normal course
of endless growth. But the debt this debacle has added to the system will
simply hasten its demise, necessary though it was. The crisis of corporate
capitalism, to put it bluntly, is not something we can grow out of, because
growth is funded by debt. And in order to grow the economy faster than it could
possibly grow in the normal course of business, Wall Street piled up layer upon
layer of debt to leverage any real assets at the bottom of the pile far beyond
the point of no return. Indeed, those real assets were buried so far beneath
the pile of debt that they were almost completely forgotten, and were virtually
meaningless to the Wall Street Rumpelstiltskins who were busy spinning gold out
of straw.
Aside from the
suffocating quantities of debt the system has generated, 2008 brought the distinct
possibility of “sudden death by derivative.” The world economy came closer to
collapse than most people realize. And we have not corrected the systemic flaws
that pushed us to the precipice. According to figures published by the only
institution that tracks the derivatives market (the Bank of International
Settlements), the size of that market—consisting of both over-the-counter and
exchange-traded derivatives—exceeded $1.1 quadrillion in July 2008.6
Yes, quadrillion. More recent estimates put it now at about $1.2 quadrillion. By
contrast, the value of the world’s financial assets—including all stock, bonds,
and bank deposits—was pegged at $294 trillion” in 2014.7 In other
words, the derivatives market is four times as large as the world’s combined
financial assets. But these financial instruments are not like stocks or bonds,
and they certainly have little similarity to bank deposits. Even though David
Korten has labeled them “phantom wealth,” they are massive in quantity and
frightening in their destructive potential.
The derivatives
market is something akin to a global casino. It consists of bets financial
speculators place in hope of winning the jackpot. These “investors” can bet on
anything from the future price of crude oil to the financial solvency of the
Port Authority of New York and New Jersey. Derivatives also include insurance
contracts on regular financial instruments such as corporate bonds. The problem
with derivatives is that they are highly leveraged, meaning that a small
foundation of real assets supports an immense tower of speculation. This is the
bubble that almost popped in 2008. In March of that year, Bear Stearns, with
derivatives valued at $13.4 trillion (larger than the U.S. national income),
almost failed. Because the financial sector is so interlinked, this would have
caused a complete systemic collapse. Disaster was averted because the Fed
allowed J .P. Morgan Chase to add the endangered Bear Stearns derivatives to
its own $77 trillion portfolio.8 Then, in September 2008, AIG and
its derivatives—called credit default swaps—almost sank the whole financial
sector.9
Investment sage Warren Buffett had good reason to call
derivatives “financial weapons of mass destruction.”10 “We view them
as time bombs,” he wrote, “both for the parties that deal in them and the
economic system.”11 This was five years before the 2008 meltdown,
which would have been catastrophic without government intervention. But the
derivative bubble still exists, and even though Congress enacted a little bit
of financial reform, the market is still largely unregulated and highly
leveraged, and the reckless Republicans want to deregulate the financial sector
even more. Go figure.
When we look at the sheer size of the derivatives market,
compared with the size of the world economy ($107.5 trillion), it is easy to
see where so much of our profit has come from. It is phantom wealth that has
been conjured into existence by leveraging real assets far beyond their ability
to ever provide the necessary level of return.
What is happening on Wall Street and elsewhere is very
consistent with the ideas of Veblen, who theorized that profit is the result of
financial manipulations by businesspeople who sabotage the system. The problem
with this method of creating profit is that it divorces the financial system
from the apparatus of production and consumption and makes profit an end in
itself. In Veblen’s world, most of the goods that clamor for our spare change
(or remaining credit) are not an end in themselves, items that people actually
need or that improve their lives. Most of the products sold in today’s market
are means to an end, and that end is profit. They were created not because we need them or even want them, but so
that someone could extort a profit from the flow. We are then persuaded
through advertising that we do indeed need or want them. In the process,
production has become a tool of finance, not the reverse.
Finance as an end in itself is a scary thing. When money
becomes the most sought-after product, something is terribly amiss because
money is no product at all. Money is a tool, a pure fiction we created to ease
the exchange of real products and labor. According to John Stuart Mill, “It is
a machine for doing quickly and commodiously, what would be done, though less
quickly and commodiously, without it; and like many other kinds of machinery,
it only exerts a distinct and independent influence of its own when it gets out
of order.”12
Money in our day has indeed gotten out of order. Because
the financial superstructure is so divorced from the practical economy,
implausible profits have been reaped and impossible though imaginary financial growth
has been experienced. But, as we have seen all too clearly, this incredible
profit and growth was really nothing more than a bubble. It popped once. And
what did we do about it? Did we put limitations in place that would prevent
another crisis? No. We restored the same flawed system, slapped its wrist, and
now the Republican Congress wants to turn it loose to do what it is designed to
do. We have created the perfect conditions for another bubble and another
collapse.
________________________
1. For a summary of Hobson’s argument, see Robert L.
Heilbroner, The Worldly Philosophers: The
Lives, Times, and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers, 6th ed. (New York:
Simon & Schuster, 1986), 194–200.
2. Heilbroner, The
Worldly Philosophers, 235.
3. Heilbroner, The
Worldly Philosophers, 235–36.
4. Heilbroner, The
Worldly Philosophers, 236.
5. Sarah Anderson et al., “Executive Excess 2008: How
Average Taxpayers Subsidize Runaway Pay,” 14th Annual CEO Compensation Survey
(Washington, DC: Institute for Policy Studies, 2008), 3.
6. Jutia Group,
“Global Derivatives Market Now Valued at $1.14 Quadrillion!” iStockAnalyst,
http://www.istockanalyst.com/article/viewarticle/articleid/2432853/. More
recent estimates peg total derivatives at $1.4 quadrillion, ample proof that
indeed we have not corrected the flaws that allowed the speculative bubble that
almost destroyed the global corporate economy in 2008.
7. Sam Ro, “Here’s
What the $294 Trillion Market of Global Financial Assets Looks Like,”
http://www.businessinsider.com/global-financial-assets-2015-2.
8. Jutia Group, “Global Derivatives Market.”
9. If you’re interested in learning more about how
derivatives work and why they almost brought the house down, a good place to
start is Adam Davidson, “How AIG Fell Apart,”
http://www.reuters.com/article/idUSMAR85972720080918.
10. Berkshire Hathaway Inc. 2002 Annual Report, 15.
11. “Introduction to Derivatives,” Global Derivatives,
http://www.global-derivatives.com/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=185.
12. John Stuart Mill, The Principles of Political Economy, 9th ed., (London: Longmans,
Green & Co., [1848], 1886), Vol. II, Book III, Chap. VII, p. 9.
A scary thought, and I think reality. To me you make a compelling case that the financial system is out of whack, and in need of serious regulation. Speculation / the derivatives market it seems has become a monster and needs to be put back in its place. I'm not an economist, but I would think by creating a ceiling/cap on profit that can be obtained through financial trade, then efforts could be realigned to where they can produce actual value. Just throwing out random numbers, but for example if one could make $50 million/year in trading, but it were capped at $1m, surely there is still enough incentive that someone would do the job that would continue to provide the balance value that financial trading market creates. Wallstreet being capped at 1/100th of it's current unregulated potential for example, I don't believe would change much of it's value output to society at large.
ReplyDeleteMy shot at an answer to your earlier questions is that in a functioning system, profits are reaped from value creation. And value is a product of work. The resources on earth left alone have a certain value, throw in work you can turn those resources into something of greater value, and with value creation or the creation of wealth, profits can be reaped.
However, I agree with the idea that within the derivatives market and throughout the financial system there seem to be many market inefficiencies that left on their own are pulling profits not from true value creation, and are therefore destroying the system, hence the need for regulation. It honestly seems like too big of a problem that I feel I can do anything about it. A bubble and a pop of that bubble almost feels inevitable. It's a depressing thought, but I don't know what else I can do besides go on my way and hope for the best.
How about instead of stumbling around in the mists of darkness you read some real economists like Mises or Rothbard who hone in on the truth. You could start with Human Action or Man, Economy and State or The Theory of Money and Credit. All are available for free on mises.org.
ReplyDelete