Corporate
capitalism is a religion. You may think this a rather fantastic statement, but
it is true nonetheless. Most adherents to the capitalist religion don’t view
themselves as religionists, but their behavior belies this view. Corporate
capitalism is an organized system with a canon of beliefs, creeds, sacraments, articles
of faith, and objects of worship. Marjorie Kelly listed several fundamental
beliefs of the corporate system:
• Stockholders must
be paid as much as possible and employees as little as possible.
• Stockholders legally
claim wealth they do little to create.
• A corporation
is piece of property—not a human community—so it can be owned and sold by the
propertied class (along with any human resources that belong to the
corporation).
• Corporations
function with an aristocratic governance structure, in which members of the
propertied class alone may vote.
• Corporate
capitalism embraces a predemocratic concept of liberty reserved to property
holders, which thrives by restricting the liberty of employees and the
community.
• Corporations
are private, and the free market will self-regulate.1
The God of Corporate Capitalism
The six beliefs listed above are
crucial to maintaining order in the Church of Corporate Capitalism, but Kelly
overlooked several tenets that are just as important, including one idea that
rises above all others. Indeed, this idea is so highly revered that we could
very well say it is universally worshipped in corporate capitalism. This one
ruling principle is endless economic growth.
How universal is
this principle? Consider the simple fact that both major political parties are
in complete agreement over this one belief: the economy must grow. The two
parties may disagree over how exactly to achieve the heaven of endless growth,
but they agree that this is the paradise we must strive for. If the economy
does not grow, then it shrivels and begins to die: profits disappear,
corporations must shed employees to cut costs, demand withers, and the cycle
starts over at a lower level, descending in a downward spiral that may
eventually end in depression, or worse. All mainstream economists and all
politicians agree on this. This is why governments attack recessions with tax
cuts or rebates, direct government investment, and bailouts of failing
companies or even whole industries. Growth is not just good; it is god. We must
worship it. We must sacrifice whatever is required to appease its volatile
anger and fickle demands. Growth is the heart and soul of the corporate
economy. Some think money is the god of capitalism, but money is just a tool.
Growth is god.
But what if
endless growth is a false god? What if it is actually the root of our economic
troubles? What if it is a road to nowhere? What if our problem is not really figuring
out how to make the current system grow faster? What if our problem is the
system itself? This is heresy of the highest order, but in this series of posts
we will consider exactly where our blind and perfect faith in the god of endless
growth will eventually take us.
Kenneth Lux, an
economic heretic, gives us a hint: “We live on a finite planet. If human beings
are defined as being made up of infinite wants [the premise behind modern
economics and corporate capitalism], and the task of an economic system is to
fulfill that infinity, then such a system will go on endlessly churning out
goods in an attempt to reach what is from the beginning an impossible goal.
When the infinite production of goods meets up with a finite planet there is
bound to be a collision.”2 We are experiencing the beginnings of
that collision today. The end result of endlessly increasing production and consumption
is a bloated system that eventually starves itself to death because it has used
up many critical resources.
But there is more
than this. We may never reach the physical limits Lux warns of. Are there
economic limits we may reach first? The enormous debt America and other
countries are accumulating suggests as much. But why can’t the national or
global economy just keep on growing forever, without end? That is the question
we must answer, but to understand the answer, we must delve into the notion of
growth itself: how it works and what its internal limitations are.
First, however,
let me make one simple observation that lies at the heart of this issue of
endless growth. If we look at a typical small business, perhaps a dry-cleaning
establishment, we observe that it can remain roughly the same size for the
entire span of its existence without any adverse effects. As long as it is
covering its costs, putting away some cash to replace aging equipment, paying
its employees a living wage, and providing for the present and future needs of
its proprietor, it doesn’t really need to grow.
A large
corporation, however, exists in an entirely different universe, operating under
different pressures and with different compulsions. If corporations don’t grow,
they generally either die or are eaten whole by other businesses. Why is this
so? Paul Hawken gives us a clue. He suggests that large corporations compete on
a different basis than small businesses.
“They are
competing against one another,” Hawken claims, “not only for the sale of
products like cars, detergent, or gasoline, but also for money, because their
growth is fueled by investment. With regard to both indebtedness and equity,
companies attempt to give the best return on investment, securing for
themselves the greatest supply of new capital at the lowest cost possible.”3
If corporations don’t provide impressive returns, they can’t access this new
capital, and often they don’t survive.
The corporate
growth imperative does hinge on the competitive nature of the corporate economy
and the fact that corporations must compete not only for sales but also for
investment, but other factors also come into play. In fact, economic growth is,
ironically, a very poorly understood concept, even though it is the god that is
universally worshipped in the corporate capitalist religion. Of course, that is
a problem with most gods. The more mysterious they remain, the greater their
allure. So let’s unveil this god of corporate capitalism.
The Profit Paradox
A few years ago, I
happened upon a website called Democratic Underground. It presented the
following hypothetical scenario:
Imagine a world with 2 “owners” &
20 “workers.”
Imagine each of the owners has $100
to “invest.”
Each buys $25 worth of raw materials
from the other ($15 “rent” cost, $10 labor cost).
Then each one pays their 10 workers
$75 to produce 20 widgets.
Imagine everyone needs some access to
a widget to sustain their life.
So, at the end of the production
cycle, we have:
20 workers with $170 dollars.
2 owners with $30 in cash & 40
widgets that cost $200 to produce, that they’ll now attempt to sell at a
profit.
Where does the profit come from?
Serious question.4
This little
scenario, like others I’ve seen, was really asking where profit comes from in
an economy. A two-company economy is just a way of simplifying things so that
we can see how transactions unfold in a large and complex economy. But the
question is still valid. The ensuing back-and-forth on Democratic Underground was
most entertaining. The person who presented the scenario, “Hannah Bell,” was
obviously playing the devil’s advocate, but most of the people posting answers
didn’t understand at all what she was asking. They were stuck on the idea that
profit is simply revenue minus expenses. That’s how an individual company makes
a profit. But Hannah was looking at the entire economy, where, on the surface,
the numbers just don’t add up.
If we look at one
company—say, Ford—its employees can never earn enough money in any particular
year to buy all the products they produce in that year. Their total wages represent
just a fraction of the total cost of Ford
vehicles produced in that year. Above and beyond Ford’s wage expense, the
company must also pay for parts, raw materials, various services, and overhead,
and still have enough left over to pay executive salaries and, in theory, put
away a little profit. So, even if you add in executive salaries, Ford’s
employees don’t make anywhere near enough money in a year to buy all the
products they produce. This is rather obvious.
But if we look at
all companies in an economy as if they were one giant corporation producing
millions of products and employing millions of people, they would be in the
same boat as Ford. The collective group of employees simply cannot earn enough
money in any given time period to buy all the products they produce. It is mathematically
impossible. If, however, we add in the all the profits earned by all
businesses, then perhaps there is enough money available to buy all the
products produced. In such a closed economy, every dollar received by any
company for the sale of its products has to come from somewhere. On the
surface, it appears that every dollar of revenue, directly or indirectly, comes
from either another organization’s expense or from its profits. In a closed
economy, then, revenues and expenses should exactly cancel each other out. This
idea has been embraced by the great worldly philosophers for centuries. If this
is true, however, then how do the majority of businesses make a profit? And how
do some reap enormous profits? Interestingly, no one has ever satisfactorily
answered this question. Yet.
But one thing
about capitalism is certain: it does grow. It does produce a collective profit.
As illogical as it might seem on the surface, the market economy not only does
grow over time, but it must grow. If the economy does not expand, it shrivels
and begins to die, as we discover anew every time we dip into recession, a
period in which we experience what economists oxymoronically call “negative
growth.” Endless growth is thus a requirement for the survival of the capitalist
market system. But, as Kenneth Lux pointed out, and as we will explore in
greater detail in a later post, endless growth is an impossibility. We
live on a finite planet with finite resources. Sooner or later the endlessly
growing economy will bump into physical constraints. But long before that
happens, the system, at least as we have imagined it, will smother itself with
debt because of certain internal conflicts.
________________________
1. Marjorie Kelly, The
Divine Right of Capital: Dethroning the Corporate Aristocracy (San
Francisco: Berrett-Koehler, 2001), 14.
2. Kenneth Lux, Adam
Smith’s Mistake: How a Moral Philosopher Invented Economics and Ended Morality
(Boston: Shambhala, 1990), 9.
3. Paul Hawken, The
Ecology of Commerce: A Declaration of Sustainability (New York:
HarperBusiness, 1993), 92–93.
4. Democratic Underground,
http://www.democraticunderground.com/discuss/duboard.php?az=view_all&address=389x3607862.
As always, I'm looking forward to your thoughts. Have you read 'The Market as God' by Harvey Cox: http://www.theatlantic.com/past/issues/99mar/marketgod.htm
ReplyDeleteIt's over 15 years old now but seems more relevant than ever. The last paragraph ties in pretty nicely with what you're saying here.
Economic growth must happen. If you assume population growth and the economy doesn't grow, then the overall standard of living goes down, which will disproportionately do more harm to those on the lower end of the income bracket.
ReplyDeleteRoger, I've enjoyed your posts over the past half year or so. However, I'm worried here that you're really tackling a strawman, when you write the following:
ReplyDelete"In a closed economy, then, revenues and expenses should exactly cancel each other out. This idea has been embraced by the great worldly philosophers for centuries. If this is true, however, then how do the majority of businesses make a profit? And how do some reap enormous profits? Interestingly, no one has ever satisfactorily answered this question."
In modern macroeconomics, I think this issue has been rigorously analyzed. It's a part of the so-called "balance of payments." Also, I'm not an expert on this issue, but I think the question you're getting at can also be framd in terms of reconciling the expenditure vs. the income method of measuring GDP and national income, respectively.
The short answer in this framework is that what you call "expenditures" should include not just material costs but also labor AND CAPITAL costs, and it's the these capital costs that are usually referred to as "profit" (net income, roughly--or cash flow to equity holders, more specifically).
Anyway, here's the basic story according to modern macro: if we ignore government and consider a closed economy, then GDP = C + I and C and I can be basically translated into revenue for firms. But this revenue then flows to households in the form of capital and labor income and then is used to either consume (C) or invest (I). (It gets more complicated because firms can also invest, but these details can and have been worked out--I'm just trying to paint a simple story here.)
Again, I like where I think you're going with this, I just think if you are able to get the economics right your point will be more convincing. (Perhaps I'm just misunderstanding you. Unfortunately, many social critics that have a similar viewpoint as you have a rather poor understanding of economics and I'm just hoping you don't make the same mistake!)
(Instead of just thinking about firms investing, it's probably easier to think of households taking their capital and labor income and either consuming or saving, and saving is basically what finances investment. So, again, K + L = C + I. Or, in words, capital and labor income equal consumption and investment expenditures. And capital income is what you are calling profit, but here profit should be understood as being closer to what operating profit is trying to capture, not net income--that is, profit here is before interest expense is subtracted, since capital income includes cash flow to both equity and debt investors. I'm not trying to be difficult, just trying to help explain!)
ReplyDelete(Oh, and regarding growth: if growth occurs, from greater productivity, let's say, then this just leads to more income--with a disproportionate increase in capital income relative to labor income, most recently--and, in turn, more expenditures in either consumption or investment. The description of national income accounting above, or what I sloppily referred to as balance of payments earlier, works with or without growth.)
ReplyDeleteThanks, Robert. I'll cover some of these ideas in future posts, but the whole growth system is troublesome in certain ways. How far it can go before it runs aground is still an open question, but we're starting to see some restrictions popping up here and there, global warming being perhaps the most troubling at present.
DeleteYes, I agree re the dangers of running aground, etc. - which is why I wanna see the critique be as accurate as possible!
Delete