A
Nation of Owners (Part 1)
Employees
are being paid to produce, not to make themselves into better people.
Corporations
are purchasing employee time to make a return on it,
not
investing in employees to enrich their lives.
Employees
are human capital, and when capital is hired or leased
the
objective is not to embellish it for its own sake but to use it for financial
advantage.
But
somewhere in this philosophy there is an inconsistency
with
the notion of a society of self-governing individuals.
The large
corporation has become an organizer of people,
a user
of people, a molder of identities, according to criteria that it has evolved,
without
regard to the effect on those people except as this is registered on the balance
sheet.
—Neil
W. Chamberlain,
The Limits of Corporate Responsibility
The first step we must take, if
we wish to design an economic system independent of growth and progress and
more tuned to serving the real needs of society, is to reconsider the most fundamental
principle of capitalism—namely, the license to accumulate unlimited capital. Limitless
ownership. This is the grand key that turns the lock on Pandora’s box and
unleashes the demons of relentless, interminable growth in our economy.
Consequently, a change in our ability to own things is the most fundamental
change we must make, a change that will affect us not only economically, but
socially and politically also, for it will serve as a first and pivotal step in
bringing the ideals that compose the American Dream back into harmony.
As
mentioned earlier, a fundamental philosophical incongruity separates the
founding principles of our nation from the economic tenets that govern modern
capitalism. This disparity would be of little consequence if its impact were
limited to the esoteric arguments of scholars. Unfortunately, this is not the
case. The incompatibility between our political ideals and our economic realities
affects each individual in society at a very personal level. Indeed, the
authoritarian nature of our economic institutions effectively prevents most
American citizens from achieving their innate potential as they seek a
fulfilling life, an equal share of liberty within the bounds of
democracy, and a true and independent sense of happiness.
Some
may choose to discount this argument, insisting that most workers prefer to be
employed from eight to five each day by someone else and are fully satisfied
with their work. This argument, however, runs counter to both common sense
about human nature and the cold, hard facts. A recent Roper poll, for instance,
found that only 18 percent of American workers consider their careers
personally and financially rewarding.1 Eighteen percent. Apparently,
spending forty hours or more each week performing tasks that someone else tells
them to perform is not so enjoyable to most Americans—especially when they are
paid the bare minimum while those who own their time live in comparative
opulence. If the rebellion in the former Soviet Bloc should have taught us
anything, it is that people do not enjoy being subject to unaccountable power.
Building
a House of Happiness
One idea we often overlook in
both politics and economics is the notion that our nation’s founding was the beginning
of a process, not the end. It was the planting of a seed, not the harvesting of
ripened fruit. The Founders changed many things, but they did not change
everything. Indeed, what they changed more than anything was direction. There
was not total agreement among the Founders on all issues and, in some ways,
more than moving toward a specific goal, they were moving away from certain
evils, establishing a system that would prevent them from cropping up again.
Unfortunately, they had no way of predicting some evils, such as the
concentration of power in large economic institutions (that in many ways
resemble the vessels of arbitrary power they so vehemently opposed). Had they
foreseen our day, they likely would have included in the Constitution specific
limitations to the accumulation of economic and not just political power.
Perhaps the Founders didn’t
totally understand the forces of societal change their Revolution had set in
motion, but they did understand one thing. They knew that the new nation would
reach its ultimate destination not in one giant leap, but in countless stages
over time. The Founders were bound by the reality that some things must change
gradually, that some ideals are beyond our present reach. This does not mean,
however, that those ideals are not worthy, or that we shouldn’t strive toward
them.
The Founders, if you will, drew
up the blueprint and laid the foundation. Later generations would then follow
that blueprint and build on that foundation, perhaps changing a few features as
circumstances warranted (this is why they provided a means for amending the
Constitution). Whether they actually got so specific as to designate what sort
of roof or veneer the structure would eventually have is both debatable and
irrelevant. They knew what kind of edifice they wanted: a free one to which
each citizen would have equal access and in which every American could reach
his or her human potential. Some of the details, they knew, an informed and
moral citizenry would have to put in place.
Unfortunately, in some ways we
are not changing in the right direction. We have tossed the Founders’ blueprint
aside and are building a sprawling prison on the foundation that was to have
supported a beautiful mansion. In our economic institutions, we have not
followed the blueprint, which included such values and principles as democracy,
equality, the sanctity of each human life, individual liberty, and the pursuit
of happiness. Instead, we have built up authoritarian economic institutions
that operate in direct conflict with the values and principles of our founding.
The industrialists and the professional executive class would have us believe
that those values and principles do not apply to economic matters, or that we
should apply them only in a token or metaphorical sense, but that is nonsense.
“As free agents,” David K. Hart
maintains, “individuals can magnify or squander the possibilities of their
lives, but those lives are sacred. Therefore, no organization, public or
private, has any right to deny, or even trivialize, the possibilities of
individual lives with organizational requirements.”2 We must
remember that the American Revolution was fought to protect individuals from
the exercise of unaccountable power in their lives. If authoritarian
institutions—be they political, social, or economic—oppress us, we can never
achieve true democracy, equality, freedom, or happiness.
As suggested in an earlier
chapter, our current belief in the idea of progress, in unbridled technological
advance and economic growth, has no overriding purpose, no end objective, no
destination. But our society, as defined by the founding values, does have an
overarching purpose: to empower each individual to achieve true happiness. We are
to arrive somewhere as American citizens, and that destination is a happy and
healthy society.
“Happiness [is] the aim of life,”
wrote Jefferson. “The happiness of society is the end of government,” John
Adams concurred. And the pursuit of happiness, which Jefferson categorized as
an unalienable right, just happens to be inseparably connected to the right to
hold property. As noted in chapter 5, the historian Paul Johnson asserts that
happiness is only achievable if people, by honest effort, can acquire property.
“Without widely dispersed property,” he adds, “true individual independence,
and so a sound Republic, [is] impossible.”3
Widely dispersed property, not
the concentration of property (and therefore power) that we see in modern
capitalism, is the precondition to happiness and a sound Republic. If our
society is to reach its true destination, if our government is to achieve its
proper end, we must address this question of ownership.
Limited
Ownership
A pivotal question, if we are
concerned with achieving personal happiness, preserving the sanctity of each
individual life, and creating a sound Republic, is the question of
ownership—and not just ownership of property and capital, but the ownership of
human time and energy, which has been labeled “human capital,” a callous and
demeaning term.
The fallacy we too often fall
into is assuming that we can correct basic inequities by either transforming
the American workplace or taking money from the wealthy and giving it to the
poor. Corporate restructuring, flattening, or reengineering; team building;
employee empowerment; and all the other buzzwords we have dreamed up to give
workers the illusion of ownership (and thus motivate them) quietly bypass the
real issue, as do all the liberal social redistribution programs. Not one of
the currently popular approaches to achieving greater equality and democracy in
the workplace addresses the fundamental obstacle to universal human happiness:
lack of true ownership. We must transform our thinking on that issue.
To put it bluntly, we must
prevent the three basic sources of authoritarian organizational control in our
lives: unlimited capital concentration, absentee ownership, and state ownership
(or state control, which is the aim of many liberal programs).
This is not a difficult problem
to solve. Using a simple process of elimination, if we refuse to allow
individuals to control large quantities of capital (and thus control the lives
of hundreds or thousands of employees), if we disallow absentee ownership
(which has created America’s new ruling class, the professional executives),
and if we don’t permit state ownership or control of industry (a fraud
perpetrated by the power hungry who insist that state ownership is really
ownership by the people), then only one alternative remains: widespread,
limited, direct ownership by the people, individually, not collectively.
Limited ownership is not a new
idea. Thomas Paine, for instance, declared in The Rights of Man (1792)
that “commerce is capable of taking care of itself,” but he also condemned “all
accumulation . . . of property, beyond what a man’s own hands produce.” This
idea of limited, universal ownership persisted well into the nineteenth
century. A mid-century labor leader named Robert MacFarlane declared that “small
but universal ownership” was the “true foundation of a stable and firm republic.”4
Three
Levels of Ownership
Limited, universal ownership of
property and the means of production is the only form of ownership that is
consistent with the founding values of the American nation. Specifically, under
a system of limited ownership, an individual would be allowed to own only as
much property as he or she could make productive use of. This is the basic
principle. It prevents an individual or group of individuals from accumulating
more property than they themselves can effectively use, which in turn prevents
them from buying time and talent and energy from the unpropertied or
disfranchised (who have nothing else to sell) to work their fields or staff
their offices or man their factories. It permits individuals, however, to
prosper to the full extent of their intelligence, talent, diligence, and
ingenuity. Above all, this principle allows every individual to own his or her
personal labor and not be required to sell it. Only the fruit of that labor,
which each individual owns, is for sale.
Although ownership based on
ability to make productive use of the thing owned is the fundamental principle
at work here, we must distinguish between different levels of use, different
levels of ownership. The Indian philosopher P. R. Sarkar suggested a
three-tiered economic system, an idea that makes good sense. The following
description is my own extrapolation from Sarkar’s basic formula.
The first level of this
three-tiered economy would consist of small enterprises that produce mainly
nonessential goods and services and perhaps a few essentials. These enterprises
would generally have a single founder or perhaps two or three, and maybe a few
“partners” who come on board somewhere downstream. To be consistent with the
guiding principle of ownership limited by contribution, each new addition to
the business would receive a share of ownership.
If a doctor needs to hire a
receptionist or a bookkeeper to make his or her practice more efficient, if a
restauranteur needs to enlist the help of waiters and waitresses, if a CPA
requires the services of a secretary or a clerk, then the new member of the
team would be given a share of ownership. Why? Because without that new member’s
contribution, the business would be less effective and a portion of the work
wouldn’t get done. But how much ownership should each new member of the
business have? An equal share? Probably not. That would not be just,
particularly in the case of a doctor or dentist or CPA who must invest much
more time to be trained than, say, a receptionist or a bookkeeper. Ownership
must also reflect seniority and other factors such as personal sacrifice,
start-up funding, and risk. Perhaps my own business can serve as an
illustration.
When a partner and I formed a
small enterprise to design and market a humorous calendar system, we determined
that we would not hire any employees, although we could very well have done
that. We agreed, simply, that if we needed help, we would bring in new
partners. But these new partners, although they would add value to our
business, wouldn’t have been there at the start. We, the two original partners,
worked and scraped and worried and sacrificed and risked bankruptcy to get the
company to the point where we would need more hands to do all the work. For
that we felt we deserved a proportionally larger share. So we developed an
ownership formula based on seniority. If you’ve put in ten years to make the
tree grow, you should own more of the fruits than someone who has put in just
two years. This formula doesn’t guarantee us twice as much ownership as new
partners, or even one and a half times as much, just a fraction more, based on
years of association. And as more partners are added, equality increases,
until, if the company ever becomes large, there will really not be much
distance between the founders and new owners.
An economic system based on this
philosophy does four things: First, it gives you incentive to find the
right outlet for your talents and energy and to stay there, because if you keep
jumping from company to company you never build equity in an enterprise, never
own a significant portion of your work. Second, it prevents you from
using people, from hiring them to do unpleasant tasks for you and paying them
as little as possible. When you’re giving a share of your company away, you
don’t do it with the intention of using someone to further your ends, because, third,
it causes you carefully to select individuals of excellent character and
ability who are willing, as it were, to jump in and get their hands dirty and
take over responsibilities you can’t handle. Consequently, fourth, it
provides a natural disincentive for companies to grow larger than they need to.
We don’t want deadwood in our company. We can’t afford it. We also don’t want
to jump into fifteen new markets with three hundred new and diverse products.
We know what we do well, and learning our own well-defined market is sufficient
challenge. If all companies had this philosophy, imagine the incentive it would
create for children in our society, who would know that if they didn’t prepare
themselves well—educationally, socially, and morally—to contribute something of
value, they wouldn’t ever find a place to make a living.
As a precaution in our business,
so that we won’t bring in a new partner who is merely putting on a good show in
the short term but would be a bad fit in the long run, we have adopted a
mandatory one-year probation period, during which any prospective partner is
guaranteed near full compensation but must prove his or her worth. If, in that
time, there arise personality conflicts or indications of moral defects or a
mismatch of skills, we can terminate the association. Or the prospective
partner can do the same if he or she doesn’t feel comfortable or happy in our
company.
Under such an arrangement, your
work colleagues become just like family. There’s more holding you together than
self-interest. You depend on one another, and you’re very careful about whom
you adopt. You also discover that you yourself can accomplish more actual
productive work than you would if you were merely somebody else’s employee (or
a manager who gets paid primarily to see that others get their work done),
because you own your work and the fruits of your labors. This type of
organization virtually eliminates dependence and replaces it with
interdependence. And it totally abolishes the tyranny that often prevails in
the world of small business.
The second level of economic activity
would consist of larger enterprises owned collectively by the “employees.” But
of course they would no longer be employees. They would now be owners. No
shares of ownership would be held by “absentee owners”—outside individuals who
do not give their time and talents and energy to the creation, marketing, or
distribution of the company’s products. This level would encompass basically
the bulk of what we now call corporate America, organizations producing
products whose efficient creation and distribution require the efforts of many
people.
Because these are large
organizations, a form of management different from that found in level-one
businesses would be necessary. Whereas level-one enterprises could operate
quite easily as true democracies, level-two organizations are often too large
for this. Pure democracy in organizations of more than, say, fifty people would
turn quickly into chaos. Rather, these organizations would have a republican
form of management, patterned after our political system. Later in this chapter
I’ll discuss this “federal model” of management in detail; for now suffice it
to say that managers would be elected by the owners.
The third level of this economic
system would consist of basic industries that benefit everyone in the
community: transportation, communication, education, defense, utilities, and so
on. These industries, more or less, belong to everyone. They are too large to
be managed effectively by cooperatives and are too important to be driven by
the profit motive. Many of them must, of necessity, be monopolies. Therefore,
they must fall in the public realm. Public boards or local governments would be
the logical bodies to manage these entities. The people who would work in these
organizations would be owners, of course, along with all other members of the
community, but they would also be public servants in the truest sense of the
word.
Let’s now take a look at an
alternative to the form of authoritarian management that at present prevails in
our economic institutions, large and small. This management model, as suggested
above, would apply primarily to the second tier of organizations in a new, more
equal system of ownership.
__________________
1.
Andrew Leckey, “Only 18% Regard Jobs as Rewarding,” Deseret News,
December 5, 1993, M, 6.
2.
David K. Hart, “Life, Liberty, and the Pursuit of Happiness: Organizational
Ethics and the Founding Values,” Exchange (BYU School of Management, Spring
1988): 5.
3.
Paul Johnson, “An Awakened Conscience.” Forbes, September 14, 1992, 183.
4. Christopher Lasch,
The True and Only Heaven (New York: Norton, 1991), 205.
No comments:
Post a Comment